友情提示:如果本网页打开太慢或显示不完整,请尝试鼠标右键“刷新”本网页!阅读过程发现任何错误请告诉我们,谢谢!! 报告错误
热门书库 返回本书目录 我的书架 我的书签 TXT全本下载 进入书吧 加入书签

the ultimate standard of value-第15章

按键盘上方向键 ← 或 → 可快速上下翻页,按键盘上的 Enter 键可回到本书目录页,按键盘上方向键 ↑ 可回到本页顶部!
————未阅读完?加入书签已便下次继续阅读!



lly; it is possible that we may be able to supply this increased demand for copper without any additional cost; or at the old rate of ten days of eighty cent labor to every hundred pounds of copper。 In this case the increased demand for copper will eventually be satisfied at this rate of cost。 The price of the copper; as well as that of the copper goods; will then have a correponding return motion until it reaches the original price of eight dollars。      But in either event; it still remains true that the price of copper goods may be determined; at least temporarily; by other conditions than their historically reckoned cost。 In practice numberless instances of this kind arise。 Even though in the long run the elementary 〃historical〃 cost plays an important part; yet time is necessary for its influence to be felt through the whole of our complicated system of production。 During this time the stage not yet effected by this leveling influence will follow the lead of their special 〃synchronous〃 cost。      Let us now take a few examples; in which this leveling influence is free to operate over a limited area of the process of production; and then at a certain point becomes permanently inoperative。      Take a chemical product; which we will assume to be sold at any given time; at its actual cost of production; say eight dollars。 Let us further assume that some discovery is made by which the cost of this material is reduced to four dollars; and that the discoverer patents the process and allows others to use it for a fee of two dollars。 The price of this product will now permanently adjust itself to a money cost of six dollars; which exceeds the elementary cost of four dollars by the amount of the patent fee or royalty of two dollars。      Let us take another case; and assume that a hundredweight of coffee; when admitted into a country free of duty; will sell at a price which is just sufficient to cover its cost of production; which we will assume to be sixty…five dollars。 Let it now be subjected to an import duty of fifteen dollars。 The price must; of course; be high enough to cover this additional cost; and; therefore; will rise to eighty dollars; an amount which exceeds the elementary cost by fifteen dollars。      Here we have two typical example of price variations; which will be found to include nearly the entire field of price phenomena; for there are at the present time very few products in which some patented machine or process; or some import duty on raw or auxiliary material does not play a part。      It is now time to ask: What has our theory to say about the determination of these price of copper kettle; chemical products; coffee; etc。?      It must offer some explanation of these facts; since they are of such frequent and general occurrence。 It is also manifest that it cannot explain them in terms of the elementary cost of labor and abstinence; nor in terms of the value of these elementary factors of cost; nor by a reference to the disutility which may be associated with the same。 The price of the copper kettle has advanced from fourteen dollars to eighteen dollars; and the price of coffee from sixty…five dollars to eighty dollars; not because; but in spite of the fact; that the elementary costs have remained unchanged at fourteen and sixty…five dollars。 Again; in the case of our chemical product; if the price depended upon the elementary cost; it should not stop at six dollars but should sink to four dollars。 It is equally clear that all these cases of price variations are subject to the law of cost and are actually effects of this law。 It would; indeed; be a very serious sin of omission; on the part of economic science; to attempt an explanation why the present prices of the several commodities mentioned in our frustration are just eighteen; six and eighty dollars; without any reference to the characteristic circumstance that these prices represent the present cost to the entrepreneur; and instead; content itself; with a vague reference to the relation existing between the supply of; and demand for these commodities。      The same considerations which in the past have forced us to supplement the general law of supply and demand through the more exact law of cost; make it necessary to so interpret the law of cost that it may include and explain the above variations in price。      What now remains to be done? In our opinion; just that which the Austrian economists have endeavored to do。      The conception of a historically reckoned cost must be brought face to face with the conception of a synchronously reckoned cost; and due importance must consciously be given to each of the two conceptions。 Thee two conceptions may; indeed; be put side by side; but are in no sense interchangeable。 For the solution of different problems in our science; both conceptions are necessary。 It is even necessary to distinguish between the different varieties of the 〃historical〃 cost。 For certain explanatory and speculative purposes; it is well to have in mind the disutility of labor。 In other cases (as in estimating certain technical advances in production); it is the quantity of labor that we must consider。 In still others; it is the value of the labor that we must inquire about。 There is not; as Professor Macvane thinks; only one 〃true conception〃 of cost。 Professor Patten; although his limitations are not entirely satisfactory; come much nearer the truth when he says that the competing concepts really belong to different branches of the theory; the one to the〃 theory of value〃 and the other to the 〃theory of prosperity。〃(44*)     Again; we must not endeavor to find in the law of cost either more or less than the Austrian economists have found in it; namely; a universal law of leveling。 And this is an influence which operate not merely upon certain final elements; but also at every stage of the productive process。 There is a leveling or equating not merely of the final elements; labor and the disutility of labor; but also of productive goods and of utility with utility。 This last takes place independent of; and ofttimes in direct opposition to the influence of the final elements。 Why; in our example of the copper kettle; does the price rise from fourteen to eighteen dollars? Simply because through the common cost it can and must be leveled to the price of the other commodities produced from copper; i。e。; in this case to the price of the strongly demanded copper wire。 But why have prices in the entire copper business advanced? Because; and in so far as; through the increased demand for copper; the marginal utility of this material has been raised。 It is; therefore; an increase in utility and not in disutility; that here in the guise of cost dictate the advance of the price。 The numerous instances of this kind which at once suggest themselves to the reader; confirm our earlier judgment of the important part which; under modern economic conditions; utility plays in the determination of cost。      It is a curious fact that the objection has been more than once advanced; that the Austrian economists have closed their eye to the rich treasure of insight and knowledge which the great law of cost affords;(45*) and that they have disdained to avail the
返回目录 上一页 下一页 回到顶部 0 0
未阅读完?加入书签已便下次继续阅读!
温馨提示: 温看小说的同时发表评论,说出自己的看法和其它小伙伴们分享也不错哦!发表书评还可以获得积分和经验奖励,认真写原创书评 被采纳为精评可以获得大量金币、积分和经验奖励哦!